Economic Man
vs.
Political Man
The word "economics" comes from two Greek words meaning
"home" + "law." Economics begins with feeding your family.
Franz Oppenheimer, in his book The
State: Its History and Development Viewed Sociologically,
distinguishes between "Economic Man" and "Political Man."
- "Economic Man" takes natural resources and
transforms them into something more useful to human beings, and under a
division of labor, trades most or all of what he produces for the fruit of
the labor of others. Both producers in such a voluntary trade are better off
than they were before the trade.
- "Political Man," on the other hand, uses force
to seize the wealth produced by "Economic Man."
Who
was Franz Oppenheimer?
Franz
Oppenheimer was born on March 30, 1864 in Berlin; he died September 30 1943 in
Los Angeles. This is not the Oppenheimer associated with the Atomic Bomb. Our
Oppenheimer exposed the mythology of the "social contract" theory of
the State, by showing its roots in conquest and violence.
Oppenheimer started out as a physician. Then he studied economics and wrote
his PhD dissertation on David
Ricardo. After accepting a call to serve as Chair for Sociology and
Theoretical Political Economy at Johann Wolfgang Goethe University in
Frankfurt/Main (the first chair dedicated to Sociology in Germany) a
cooperative agricultural community of individual farms (called a "Moshav")
was founded by Jews using Oppenheimer's blueprint. Oppenheimer later taught in
Palestine. He fled Nazi persecution to Los Angeles, and became a founding
member of The American Journal of Economics and
Sociology.
Oppenheimer's book The
State looks
at the origins of this political entity:
"The State, completely in its genesis, essentially and almost
completely during the first stages of its existence, is a social
institution, forced by a victorious group of men on a defeated group, with
the sole purpose of regulating the dominion of the victorious group over the
vanquished, and securing itself against revolt from within and attacks from
abroad. Teleologically, this dominion had no other purpose than the economic
exploitation of the vanquished by the victors."
"No primitive state known to history originated in any other manner.
Wherever a reliable tradition reports otherwise, either it concerns the
amalgamation of two fully developed primitive states into one body of more
complete organisation, or else it is an adaptation to men of the fable of
the sheep which made a bear their king in order to be protected against the
wolf. But even in this latter case, the form and content of the State became
precisely the same as in those states where nothing intervened, and which
became immediately 'wolf states'." (p. 15)
Economic Man and Political Man
Oppenheimer made the compelling observation:
"There are two fundamentally opposed means whereby man, requiring
sustenance, is impelled to obtain the necessary means for satisfying his
desires. These are work and robbery, one's own labor and the forcible
appropriation of the labor of others. Robbery! Forcible appropriation! These
words convey to us ideas of crime and the penitentiary, since we are the
contemporaries of a developed civilization, specifically based on the
inviolability of property. And this tang is not lost when we are convinced
that land and sea robbery is the primitive relation of life, just as the
warrior's trade - which also for a long time is only organized mass robbery
- constitutes the most respected of occupations. Both because of this, and
also on account of the need of having, in the further development of this
study, terse, clear, sharply opposing terms for these very important
contrasts, I propose in the following discussion to call one's own labor and
the equivalent exchange of one's own labor for the labor of others, the “economic
means" for the satisfaction of needs, while the unrequited
appropriation of the labor of others will be called the "political
means." (pp. 24-25)
Albert Jay Nock introduced these concepts to American readers in his own book
Our
Enemy, the State.
h/t Wikipedia
Albert Jay Nock and the
Libertarian Tradition - Jeff Riggenbach - Mises Daily
One such question was, what is the nature of the state? Where did it come
from? If the state was in fact useless for the purpose of improving human
society what was it in fact good for? So he wrote a book. It's called Our
Enemy, the State. It came out in 1935, after being delivered as a series
of lectures at Nock's newly renamed alma mater, Bard College. Our
Enemy, the State is a true libertarian classic, one of those books you
simply must read if you have any serious interest at all in the
libertarian idea.
The state, Nock wrote,
did not originate in the common understanding and agreement of society; it
originated in conquest and confiscation. Its intention, far from contemplating
"freedom and security," contemplated nothing of the kind. It
contemplated primarily the continuous economic exploitation of one class by
another, and it concerned itself with only so much freedom and security as was
consistent with this primary intention; and this was, in fact, very little.
Its primary function or exercise was … maintaining the stratification of
society into an owning and exploiting class, and a propertyless dependent
class. The order of interest that it reflected was not social, but purely
antisocial; and those who administered it, judged by the common standard of
ethics, or even the common standard of law as applied to private persons, were
indistinguishable from a professional-criminal class. …
The positive testimony of history is that the State invariably had its
origin in conquest and confiscation. No primitive State known to history
originated in any other manner … no primitive State could possibly have had
any other origin. Moreover, the sole invariable characteristic of the State is
the economic exploitation of one class by another.
Nock quotes the German sociologist Franz Oppenheimer, who described the
typical primitive state,
in respect of its origin, as an institution "forced on a defeated
group by a conquering group, with a view only to systematizing the domination
of the conquered by the conquerors, and safeguarding itself against
insurrection from within and attack from without. This domination had no other
final purpose than the economic exploitation of the conquered group by the
victorious group."
Nock wrote,
Any considerable economic accumulation, or any considerable body of natural
resources, is an incentive to conquest. The primitive technique was that of
raiding the coveted possessions, appropriating them entire, and either
exterminating the possessors, or dispersing them beyond convenient reach. Very
early, however, it was seen to be in general more profitable to reduce the
possessors to dependence, and use them as labour-motors. … [This] modified
technique has been in use almost from the beginning, and everywhere its first
appearance marks the origin of the State. …
The State, both in its genesis and by its primary intention, is purely
anti-social. It is not based on the idea of natural rights, but on the idea
that the individual has no rights except those that the State may
provisionally grant him. It has always made justice costly and difficult of
access, and has invariably held itself above justice and common morality
whenever it could advantage itself by so doing.
In essence, then, "taking the State wherever found, striking into its
history at any point, one sees no way to differentiate the activities of its
founders, administrators and beneficiaries from those of a professional-criminal
class."
After all, Nock argued, there are two and only two means of making a living
in this world. There's the economic means — earning it. And there's the
political means — seizing it from someone else who has earned it. The state,
Nock said, is "the organization of the political means."
Does this sound familiar somehow? Does it sound, perhaps, like the rhetoric
of Mr. Libertarian, Murray N. Rothbard? Nock had an immense influence on
Rothbard. He also had an immense influence, apparently, on another major figure
in the contemporary libertarian movement, Ayn Rand. According to Anne C. Heller,
whose biography of Rand, Ayn
Rand and the World She Made, was published about a year ago, it was the
theory Nock had adapted from Franz Oppenheimer that inspired Rand to write The
Fountainhead.